-4- Foreign Trade Aside from the stimulating effect on the economy of a large-scale arms aid and defense program, we believe that the foreign situation will provide a progressively less dynamic element in domestic business. In the period immeidately after the war, United States exports rose to an annual rate of almost $18 billion, largely as a result of foreign spending of gold and dollar reserves accumulated during the war. As these reserves were dissipated, exports of about $13 billion were made possible by Government grants and loans, together with some increase of imports. The supporting effect of a high rate of exports, as well as a $6 billion gap between imports and exports, will decline as Marshall Plan aid tapers off, although supplementary aid programs may prove expedient for some years to come. There is widespread hope that the recent devaluation of currencies will prove to be a turning point for the better in European trade but whether or not this hope will be justified depends upon many unpredictable factors. Devaluation will undoubtedly produce immediate benefits to the countries involved, particularly England. It has stopped, and at least for the time being has reversed, the drain on Britain's gold and dollar reserves which was proceeding at an accelerated pace throughout the summer. In anticipation of devaluation many owners of sterling were converting either into goods or hard currencies through gray markets, and purchasers from hard currency areas withheld orders for sterling goods in the hope of placing them at a lower sterling rate. Owners of sterling throughout the world are now less anxious to rid themselves of holdings at the $2.80 level, which is in line with gray market quotations before devaluation. The new, more realistic exchange rates should permit reduction of administrative controls, multiple price systems and other barriers to trade. The competitive position of soft currency products should be improved in American and other hard currency markets. Although these benefits are well worth while, the restoration of a sound British financial position will depend upon the solution of many more fundamental problems,chiefly the ability to reduce costs, improve production and merchandise goods effectively in hard currency areas. Cost can be held down only if internal inflation can be checked. This is particularly hard to accomplish at a time when Britain's policies are for political purposes directed toward maintaining sizable public benefits. While the interval since devaluation has been too short to be conclusive, there is little evidence to date that the Labor government means to tackle the cost problem realistically. Greater productivity requires not only continued high expenditures for modernization of plant but also persuasion of both management and labor to work more efficiently. To improve sales to the dollar area it will be necessary also to persuade manufacturers of goods in Britain to seek outlets in this market in preference to long-established markets which are predominantly in soft currency areas. Since there is already full employment in England, increased exports to hard currency countries cannot be obtained merely by putting idle plant and people to work. Accordingly, if new price relationships caused by devaluation do not cause a shift in existing trade relationships, the government may be forced to new kinds of incentives for sales to hard currency areas, such as the recently announced assistance on merchandising costs. Downward revision of sterling war debts if accomplished should serve to reduce the pressure to ship goods to soft currency areas in partial payment. Over the longer term the major requirement for recovery of world trade is at least partial convertibility of currencies. Until there is an approach to a better balance of trade among nations and general confidence in |